Ítem
Acceso Abierto

More public goods, more political reciprocity? Evidence from a post-conflict economy
dc.contributor.advisor | Seither Afonso, Julia | |
dc.contributor.advisor | Vargas Duque, Juan Fernando | |
dc.creator | Garzón Restrepo, Juan Esteban | |
dc.creator.degree | Magíster en Economía | |
dc.creator.degreeLevel | Maestría | |
dc.creator.degreetype | Full time | |
dc.date.accessioned | 2024-01-11T20:47:59Z | |
dc.date.available | 2024-01-11T20:47:59Z | |
dc.date.created | 2023-12-14 | |
dc.description | While a large literature defines and diagnoses the effects of weak institutions, much less is known about how to improve them. In developing countries, there are often many signs of weak institutions that undermine reciprocal behavior between the population and the state. This paper studies the effect of community-driven post-conflict development programs in Colombia (called PDET) on citizen's reciprocal behavior, especially tax compliance and participation in social mobilization. To the extent that PDET affects these outcomes, I document the extent to which these type of programs improve state capacity. Using a \textit{difference-in-differences} strategy, I compare municipalities with a close probability of being treated with treated ones to estimate causal effects. The results (due to data restrictions) show a short-term increase on protests fostered by weak institutions characteristics of the treated municipalities. On the other hand, tax revenue is influenced by an upsurge in property and sales taxes. This effect may be attributed to factors related to tax compliance, but it is not the sole plausible explanation. This provides evidence on how governments can generate new relationships on state capacity and tax compliance with historically harmful pasts societies. | |
dc.description.abstract | While a large literature defines and diagnoses the effects of weak institutions, much less is known about how to improve them. In developing countries, there are often many signs of weak institutions that undermine reciprocal behavior between the population and the state. This paper studies the effect of community-driven post-conflict development programs in Colombia (called PDET) on citizen's reciprocal behavior, especially tax compliance and participation in social mobilization. To the extent that PDET affects these outcomes, I document the extent to which these type of programs improve state capacity. Using a \textit{difference-in-differences} strategy, I compare municipalities with a close probability of being treated with treated ones to estimate causal effects. The results (due to data restrictions) show a short-term increase on protests fostered by weak institutions characteristics of the treated municipalities. On the other hand, tax revenue is influenced by an upsurge in property and sales taxes. This effect may be attributed to factors related to tax compliance, but it is not the sole plausible explanation. This provides evidence on how governments can generate new relationships on state capacity and tax compliance with historically harmful pasts societies. | |
dc.format.extent | 38 pp | |
dc.format.mimetype | application/pdf | |
dc.identifier.doi | https://doi.org/10.48713/10336_41974 | |
dc.identifier.uri | https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/41974 | |
dc.language.iso | spa | |
dc.publisher | Universidad del Rosario | spa |
dc.publisher.department | Facultad de Economía | spa |
dc.publisher.program | Maestría en Economía | spa |
dc.rights | Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International | * |
dc.rights.accesRights | info:eu-repo/semantics/openAccess | |
dc.rights.acceso | Abierto (Texto Completo) | |
dc.rights.licencia | EL AUTOR, manifiesta que la obra objeto de la presente autorización es original y la realizó sin violar o usurpar derechos de autor de terceros, por lo tanto la obra es de exclusiva autoría y tiene la titularidad sobre la misma. PARGRAFO: En caso de presentarse cualquier reclamación o acción por parte de un tercero en cuanto a los derechos de autor sobre la obra en cuestión, EL AUTOR, asumirá toda la responsabilidad, y saldrá en defensa de los derechos aquí autorizados; para todos los efectos la universidad actúa como un tercero de buena fe. EL AUTOR, autoriza a LA UNIVERSIDAD DEL ROSARIO, para que en los términos establecidos en la Ley 23 de 1982, Ley 44 de 1993, Decisión andina 351 de 1993, Decreto 460 de 1995 y demás normas generales sobre la materia, utilice y use la obra objeto de la presente autorización. -------------------------------------- POLITICA DE TRATAMIENTO DE DATOS PERSONALES. Declaro que autorizo previa y de forma informada el tratamiento de mis datos personales por parte de LA UNIVERSIDAD DEL ROSARIO para fines académicos y en aplicación de convenios con terceros o servicios conexos con actividades propias de la academia, con estricto cumplimiento de los principios de ley. Para el correcto ejercicio de mi derecho de habeas data cuento con la cuenta de correo habeasdata@urosario.edu.co, donde previa identificación podré solicitar la consulta, corrección y supresión de mis datos. | spa |
dc.rights.uri | http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ | * |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Abadie, A., & Imbens, G. W. (2016). Matching on the estimated propensity score. Econometrica, 84 (2), 781–807. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Acemoglu, D. (2005). Politics and economics in weak and strong states. Journal of monetary Economics, 52 (7), 1199–1226. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2017). The emergence of weak, despotic and inclusive states (Tech. Rep.). National Bureau of Economic Research. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J. A., & Santos, R. J. (2013). The monopoly of violence: Evidence from colombia. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11 (suppl 1), 5–44. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 (2), 565–611. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Belloni, A., Chernozhukov, V., & Hansen, C. (2014, May). High-dimensional methods and inference on structural and treatment effects. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28 (2), 29-50. Retrieved from https://www .aeaweb .org/articles ?id=10 .1257/jep .28 .2 .29 DOI: 10.1257/jep.28.2.29 | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Bernal, C., Prem, M., Vargas, J. F., & Ortiz, M. (2023). Peaceful entry: Entrepreneurship dynamics during colombia’s peace agreement. Journal of Development Economics, 103119. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Besley, T. (2020). State capacity, reciprocity, and the social contract. Econometrica, 88 (4), 1307– 1335. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American economic review , 99 (4), 1218–1244. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2010). State capacity, conflict, and development. Econometrica, 78 (1), 1–34. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2014). Why do developing countries tax so little? Journal of economic perspectives, 28 (4), 99–120. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Dalton, R. J. (2013). Citizen politics: Public opinion and political parties in advanced industrial democracies. Cq Press. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Fergusson, L. (2019). Who wants violence? the political economy of conflict and state building in colombia. Cuadernos de Econom ́ıa, 38 (78), 671–699. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Fergusson, L., Molina, C. A., & Robinson, J. A. (2022). The weak state trap. Economica, 89 (354), 293–331. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Fergusson, L., Querubin, P., Ruiz, N. A., & Vargas, J. F. (2021). The real winner’s curse. American Journal of Political Science, 65 (1), 52–68. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Fergusson, L., Robinson, J. A., Torvik, R., & Vargas, J. F. (2016). The need for enemies. The Economic Journal , 126 (593), 1018–1054. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Gelvez-Ferreira, J., & Johnson, M. (2023). “los nadies y las nadies”: The effect of peace-building on political behavior in colombia. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Kalyvas, S. N. (2006). The logic of violence in civil war. Cambridge University Press. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Machado, F., Scartascini, C., & Tommasi, M. (2011). Political institutions and street protests in latin america. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55 (3), 340–365. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Namen, O., Prem, M., Vargas, J. F., et al. (2020). The human capital peace dividend. Forthcoming at Journal of Human Resources. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Oquist, P. H. (1980). Violence, conflict, and politics in colombia. Academic Press. Retrieved from http://ez.urosario.edu.co/login?url=https://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&AuthType=ip&db=edshlc&AN=edshlc.000917600.4&lang=es&site=eds-live&scope=site | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Perilla, S., Prem, M., Purroy, M. E., & Vargas, J. F. (2022). How peace saves lives: Evidence from colombia. Available at SSRN 3977483 . | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2002). Political economics: explaining economic policy. MIT press. Registro ́Unico de v ́ıctimas. (2023). https://www.unidadvictimas.gov.co/es/registro-unico -de-victimas-ruv-34487. (Accessed: 25 05 2023) | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Scartascini, C., & Tommasi, M. (2012). The making of policy: institutionalized or not? American Journal of Political Science, 56 (4), 787–801. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Sobel, J. (2005). Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. Journal of economic literature, 43 (2), 392–436. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Tabellini, G. (2008). The scope of cooperation: Values and incentives. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123 (3), 905–950. | |
dc.source.bibliographicCitation | Tibshirani, R. (1996). Regression shrinkage and selection via the lasso. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B: Statistical Methodology, 58 (1), 267–288. | |
dc.source.instname | instname:Universidad del Rosario | |
dc.source.reponame | reponame:Repositorio Institucional EdocUR | |
dc.subject | State capacity | |
dc.subject | Intrinsic reciprocity | |
dc.subject | Peace agreement | |
dc.subject | Public goods | |
dc.subject | Colombia | |
dc.subject.keyword | State capacity | |
dc.subject.keyword | Intrinsic reciprocity | |
dc.subject.keyword | Peace agreement | |
dc.subject.keyword | Public goods | |
dc.subject.keyword | Colombia | |
dc.title | More public goods, more political reciprocity? Evidence from a post-conflict economy | |
dc.title.TranslatedTitle | ¿Más bienes públicos, más reciprocidad política? Datos de una economía en situación de post-conflicto | |
dc.type | bachelorThesis | |
dc.type.document | Trabajo de grado | |
dc.type.hasVersion | info:eu-repo/semantics/acceptedVersion | |
dc.type.spa | Trabajo de grado | |
local.department.report | Facultad de Economía |
Archivos
Bloque original
1 - 1 de 1
Cargando...
- Nombre:
- Evidence_from_a_post_conflict_economy_Garzón_Restrepo_Juan_Esteban.pdf
- Tamaño:
- 2.13 MB
- Formato:
- Adobe Portable Document Format
- Descripción: